Share to: share facebook share twitter share wa share telegram print page

Ecological fallacy

An ecological fallacy (also ecological inference fallacy[1] or population fallacy) is a formal fallacy in the interpretation of statistical data that occurs when inferences about the nature of individuals are deduced from inferences about the group to which those individuals belong. "Ecological fallacy" is a term that is sometimes used to describe the fallacy of division, which is not a statistical fallacy. The four common statistical ecological fallacies are: confusion between ecological correlations and individual correlations, confusion between group average and total average, Simpson's paradox, and confusion between higher average and higher likelihood. From a statistical point of view, these ideas can be unified by specifying proper statistical models to make formal inferences, using aggregate data to make unobserved relationships in individual level data.[2]

Examples

Mean and median

An example of ecological fallacy is the assumption that a population mean has a simple interpretation when considering likelihoods for an individual.

For instance, if the mean score of a group is larger than zero, this does not imply that a random individual of that group is more likely to have a positive score than a negative one (as long as there are more negative scores than positive scores an individual is more likely to have a negative score). Similarly, if a particular group of people is measured to have a lower mean IQ than the general population, it is an error to conclude that a randomly-selected member of the group is more likely than not to have a lower IQ than the mean IQ of the general population; it is also not necessarily the case that a randomly selected member of the group is more likely than not to have a lower IQ than a randomly-selected member of the general population. Mathematically, this comes from the fact that a distribution can have a positive mean but a negative median. This property is linked to the skewness of the distribution.

Consider the following numerical example:

  • Group A: 80% of people got 40 points and 20% of them got 95 points. The mean score is 51 points.
  • Group B: 50% of people got 45 points and 50% got 55 points. The mean score is 50 points.
  • If we pick two people at random from A and B, there are 4 possible outcomes:
    • A – 40, B – 45 (B wins, 40% probability – 0.8 × 0.5)
    • A – 40, B – 55 (B wins, 40% probability – 0.8 × 0.5)
    • A – 95, B – 45 (A wins, 10% probability – 0.2 × 0.5)
    • A – 95, B – 55 (A wins, 10% probability – 0.2 × 0.5)
  • Although Group A has a higher mean score, 80% of the time a random individual of A will score lower than a random individual of B.

Individual and aggregate correlations

Research dating back to Émile Durkheim suggests that predominantly Protestant localities have higher suicide rates than predominantly Catholic localities.[3] According to Freedman,[4] the idea that Durkheim's findings link, at an individual level, a person's religion to their suicide risk is an example of the ecological fallacy. A group-level relationship does not automatically characterize the relationship at the level of the individual.

Similarly, even if at the individual level, wealth is positively correlated to tendency to vote Republican in the United States, we observe that wealthier states tend to vote Democratic. For example, in the 2004 United States presidential election, the Republican candidate, George W. Bush, won the fifteen poorest states, and the Democratic candidate, John Kerry, won 9 of the 11 wealthiest states in the Electoral College. Yet 62% of voters with annual incomes over $200,000 voted for Bush, but only 36% of voters with annual incomes of $15,000 or less voted for Bush.[5] Aggregate-level correlation will differ from individual-level correlation if voting preferences are affected by the total wealth of the state even after controlling for individual wealth. The true driving factor in voting preference could be self-perceived relative wealth; perhaps those who see themselves as better off than their neighbours are more likely to vote Republican. In this case, an individual would be more likely to vote Republican if they became wealthier, but they would be more likely to vote for a Democrat if their neighbor's wealth increased (resulting in a wealthier state).

However, the observed difference in voting habits based on state- and individual-level wealth could also be explained by the common confusion between higher averages and higher likelihoods as discussed above. States may not be wealthier because they contain more wealthy people (i.e., more people with annual incomes over $200,000), but rather because they contain a small number of super-rich individuals; the ecological fallacy then results from incorrectly assuming that individuals in wealthier states are more likely to be wealthy.

Many examples of ecological fallacies can be found in studies of social networks, which often combine analysis and implications from different levels. This has been illustrated in an academic paper on networks of farmers in Sumatra.[6]

Robinson's paradox

A 1950 paper by William S. Robinson computed the illiteracy rate and the proportion of the population born outside the US for each state and for the District of Columbia, as of the 1930 census.[7] He showed that these two figures were associated with a negative correlation of −0.53; in other words, the greater the proportion of immigrants in a state, the lower its average illiteracy (or, equivalently, the higher its average literacy). However, when individuals are considered, the correlation between illiteracy and nativity was +0.12 (immigrants were on average more illiterate than native citizens). Robinson showed that the negative correlation at the level of state populations was because immigrants tended to settle in states where the native population was more literate. He cautioned against deducing conclusions about individuals on the basis of population-level, or "ecological" data. In 2011, it was found that Robinson's calculations of the ecological correlations are based on the wrong state level data. The correlation of −0.53 mentioned above is in fact −0.46.[8] Robinson's paper was seminal, but the term 'ecological fallacy' was not coined until 1958 by Selvin.[9]

Formal problem

The correlation of aggregate quantities (or ecological correlation) is not equal to the correlation of individual quantities. Denote by XiYi two quantities at the individual level. The formula for the covariance of the aggregate quantities in groups of size N is

The covariance of two aggregated variables depends not only on the covariance of two variables within the same individuals but also on covariances of the variables between different individuals. In other words, correlation of aggregate variables take into account cross sectional effects which are not relevant at the individual level.

The problem for correlations entails naturally a problem for regressions on aggregate variables: the correlation fallacy is therefore an important issue for a researcher who wants to measure causal impacts. Start with a regression model where the outcome is impacted by

The regression model at the aggregate level is obtained by summing the individual equations:

Nothing prevents the regressors and the errors from being correlated at the aggregate level. Therefore, generally, running a regression on aggregate data does not estimate the same model than running a regression with individual data.

The aggregate model is correct if and only if

This means that, controlling for , does not determine .

Choosing between aggregate and individual inference

There is nothing wrong in running regressions on aggregate data if one is interested in the aggregate model. For instance, for the governor of a state, it is correct to run regressions between police force on crime rate at the state level if one is interested in the policy implication of a rise in police force. However, an ecological fallacy would happen if a city council deduces the impact of an increase in police force in the crime rate at the city level from the correlation at the state level.

Choosing to run aggregate or individual regressions to understand aggregate impacts on some policy depends on the following trade-off: aggregate regressions lose individual-level data but individual regressions add strong modeling assumptions. Some researchers suggest that the ecological correlation gives a better picture of the outcome of public policy actions, thus they recommend the ecological correlation over the individual level correlation for this purpose (Lubinski & Humphreys, 1996). Other researchers disagree, especially when the relationships among the levels are not clearly modeled. To prevent ecological fallacy, researchers with no individual data can model first what is occurring at the individual level, then model how the individual and group levels are related, and finally examine whether anything occurring at the group level adds to the understanding of the relationship. For instance, in evaluating the impact of state policies, it is helpful to know that policy impacts vary less among the states than do the policies themselves, suggesting that the policy differences are not well translated into results, despite high ecological correlations (Rose, 1973).

Group and total averages

Ecological fallacy can also refer to the following fallacy: the average for a group is approximated by the average in the total population divided by the group size. Suppose one knows the number of Protestants and the suicide rate in the USA, but one does not have data linking religion and suicide at the individual level. If one is interested in the suicide rate of Protestants, it is a mistake to estimate it by the total suicide rate divided by the number of Protestants. Formally, denote the mean of the group, we generally have:

However, the law of total probability gives

As we know that is between 0 and 1, this equation gives a bound for .

Simpson's paradox

A striking ecological fallacy is Simpson's paradox: the fact that when comparing two populations divided into groups, the average of some variable in the first population can be higher in every group and yet lower in the total population. Formally, when each value of Z refers to a different group and X refers to some treatment, it can happen that

When does not depend on , the Simpson's paradox is exactly the omitted variable bias for the regression of Y on X where the regressor is a dummy variable and the omitted variable is a categorical variable defining groups for each value it takes. The application is striking because the bias is high enough that parameters have opposite signs.

Legal applications

The ecological fallacy was discussed in a court challenge to the 2004 Washington gubernatorial election in which a number of illegal voters were identified, after the election; their votes were unknown, because the vote was by secret ballot. The challengers argued that illegal votes cast in the election would have followed the voting patterns of the precincts in which they had been cast, and thus adjustments should be made accordingly.[10] An expert witness said this approach was like trying to figure out Ichiro Suzuki's batting average by looking at the batting average of the entire Seattle Mariners team, since the illegal votes were cast by an unrepresentative sample of each precinct's voters, and might be as different from the average voter in the precinct as Ichiro was from the rest of his team.[11] The judge determined that the challengers' argument was an ecological fallacy and rejected it.[12]

See also

References

  1. ^ Charles Ess; Fay Sudweeks (2001). Culture, technology, communication: towards an intercultural global village. SUNY Press. p. 90. ISBN 978-0-7914-5015-4. The problem lies with the 'ecological fallacy' (or fallacy of division)—the impulse to apply group or societal level characteristics to individuals within that group.
  2. ^ King, Gary (1997). A Solution to the Ecological Inference Problem. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-01240-7.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: date and year (link)
  3. ^ Durkheim, (1951/1897). Suicide: A study in sociology. Translated by John A. Spaulding and George Simpson. New York: The Free Press. ISBN 0-684-83632-7.
  4. ^ Freedman, D. A. (1999). Ecological Inference and the Ecological Fallacy. International Encyclopedia of the Social & Behavioral Sciences, Technical Report No. 549. https://web.stanford.edu/class/ed260/freedman549.pdf
  5. ^ Gelman, Andrew; Park, David; Shor, Boris; Bafumi, Joseph; Cortina, Jeronimo (2008). Red State, Blue State, Rich State, Poor State. Princeton University Press. ISBN 978-0-691-13927-2.
  6. ^ Matous, Petr (2015). "Social networks and environmental management at multiple levels: soil conservation in Sumatra". Ecology and Society. 20 (3): 37. doi:10.5751/ES-07816-200337. hdl:10535/9990.
  7. ^ Robinson, W.S. (1950). "Ecological Correlations and the Behavior of Individuals". American Sociological Review. 15 (3): 351–357. doi:10.2307/2087176. JSTOR 2087176.
  8. ^ The research note on this curious data glitch is published in Te Grotenhuis, Manfred; Eisinga, Rob; Subramanian, S.V. (2011). "Robinson's Ecological Correlations and the Behavior of Individuals: methodological corrections". Int J Epidemiol. 40 (4): 1123–1125. doi:10.1093/ije/dyr081. hdl:2066/99678. PMID 21596762. The data Robinson used and the corrections are available at http://www.ru.nl/mt/rob/downloads/
  9. ^ Selvin, Hanan C. (1958). "Durkheim's Suicide and Problems of Empirical Research". American Journal of Sociology. 63 (6): 607–619. doi:10.1086/222356. S2CID 143488519.
  10. ^ George Howland Jr. (May 18, 2005). "The Monkey Wrench Trial: Dino Rossi's challenge of the 2004 election is on shaky legal ground. But if he prevails, watch litigation become an option in close races everywhere". Seattle Weekly. Archived from the original on December 1, 2008. Retrieved December 17, 2008.
  11. ^ Christopher Adolph (May 12, 2005). "Report on the 2004 Washington Gubernatorial Election". Expert witness report to the Chelan County Superior Court in Borders et al v. King County et al.
  12. ^ Borders et al. v. King County et al. Archived 2008-10-18 at the Wayback Machine, transcript of the decision by Chelan County Superior Court Judge John Bridges, June 6, 2005, published: June 8, 2005

Further reading

Read more information:

Rumpun Tidung terdiri atas: Ulun Pagun (wilayah pesisir) Ulun Bulungan (wilayah pesisir) Ulun Tenggalan (wilayah pedalaman) Ulun Tagol (wilayah pedalaman) Ulun Berusu (wilayah pedalaman) Pranala luar http://www.tidungceria.com Diarsipkan 2012-10-04 di Wayback Machine. Artikel bertopik Indonesia ini adalah sebuah rintisan. Anda dapat membantu Wikipedia dengan mengembangkannya.lbs

Artikel ini tidak memiliki referensi atau sumber tepercaya sehingga isinya tidak bisa dipastikan. Tolong bantu perbaiki artikel ini dengan menambahkan referensi yang layak. Tulisan tanpa sumber dapat dipertanyakan dan dihapus sewaktu-waktu.Cari sumber: Tugu Pensil Kulon Progo – berita · surat kabar · buku · cendekiawan · JSTOR Tugu Pensil Kulon Progoꦠꦸꦒꦸꦥꦺꦴꦠ꧀ꦭꦺꦴꦠ꧀ꦏꦸꦭꦺꦴꦤ꧀ꦥꦿꦒJenisTugu ikonikLokasiDusun Kenteng…

This is a list of bridges and tunnels on the National Register of Historic Places in the U.S. state of Massachusetts.[1] Name Image Built Listed Location County Type Annisquam Bridge 1861, 1896, 1961 1983-06-23 Gloucester42°39′18″N 70°40′32.4″W / 42.65500°N 70.675667°W / 42.65500; -70.675667 (Annisquam Bridge) Essex Wood pile type Atherton Bridge 1870 1979-09-19 Lancaster42°26′40″N 71°40′21″W / 42.44444°N 71.67250°W&…

Wakil Bupati CilacapPetahanaSyamsul Aulia Rachman, S.STP., M.Si.sejak 19 November 2017Masa jabatan5 tahunDibentuk2002Pejabat pertamaTohirin BahriSitus webcilacapkab.go.id/v3/ Berikut ini adalah daftar Wakil Bupati Cilacap dari masa ke masa. No Wakil Bupati Mulai Jabatan Akhir Jabatan Prd. Ket. Bupati 1 H.Tohirin BahriB.A. 2002 2007 1   H.Probo YulastoroS.Sos., M.M., M.Si. 2 H.Tatto Suwarto Pamuji 2007 2009 2   Jabatan kosong 2009 15 Mei 2011   H.Tatto Suwarto Pamuji(Pelaksana…

Village in SerbiaCaparić Цапарић (Serbian)Village (Selo)CaparićCoordinates: 44°10′N 19°28′E / 44.167°N 19.467°E / 44.167; 19.467Country SerbiaMunicipalityLjubovijaTime zoneUTC+1 (CET) • Summer (DST)UTC+2 (CEST) Caparić (Serbian Cyrillic: Цапарић) is a village in Serbia. It is situated in the Ljubovija municipality, in the Mačva District of Central Serbia. The village has a Serb ethnic majority. It had a population of 448 in …

قرية برغن     الإحداثيات 43°05′00″N 77°56′30″W / 43.0833°N 77.9417°W / 43.0833; -77.9417  [1] تاريخ التأسيس 1801  تقسيم إداري  البلد الولايات المتحدة[2]  خصائص جغرافية  المساحة 0.74 ميل مربع  ارتفاع 606 قدم  عدد السكان  عدد السكان 1208 (1 أبريل 2020)[3]  الكثاف…

Si ce bandeau n'est plus pertinent, retirez-le. Cliquez ici pour en savoir plus. Cet article ne cite pas suffisamment ses sources (octobre 2016). Si vous disposez d'ouvrages ou d'articles de référence ou si vous connaissez des sites web de qualité traitant du thème abordé ici, merci de compléter l'article en donnant les références utiles à sa vérifiabilité et en les liant à la section « Notes et références » En pratique : Quelles sources sont attendues ? Comme…

Election in Ohio Main article: 1932 United States presidential election 1932 United States presidential election in Ohio ← 1928 November 8, 1932 1936 →   Nominee Franklin D. Roosevelt Herbert Hoover Party Democratic Republican Home state New York California Running mate John Nance Garner Charles Curtis Electoral vote 26 0 Popular vote 1,301,695 1,227,319 Percentage 49.88% 47.03% County Results Roosevelt   40-50%   50-60%  &#…

Cet article est une ébauche concernant la Nouvelle-Zélande et une université. Vous pouvez partager vos connaissances en l’améliorant (comment ?) selon les recommandations des projets correspondants. Université de CanterburyHistoireFondation 1873StatutType Université publiqueNom officiel University of CanterburyTe Whare Wānanga o WaitahaRégime linguistique AnglaisDevise Ergo tua rura manebuntMembre de ORCID (d)Site web www.canterbury.ac.nzChiffres-clésÉtudiants 18 771 (2020)…

Prealpi GiulieI monti MusiContinenteEuropa Stati Italia Slovenia Catena principaleAlpi e Prealpi Giulie (nelle Alpi) Cima più elevatamonte Plauris (1.958 m s.l.m.) Massicci principaliPrealpi Giulie SettentrionaliPrealpi Giulie Meridionali Le Prealpi Giulie sono un insieme di rilievi montuosi che interessano l'Italia e la Slovenia, situati a cavallo del confine tra la regione italiana del Friuli-Venezia Giulia e la regione slovena del Goriziano. Confinano con le Alpi Giulie a…

2015 song by Madonna For the instrumental composition by The Corrs, see Rebel Heart (instrumental). For other songs, see Rebel Heart (disambiguation). Rebel HeartSong by Madonnafrom the album Rebel Heart ReleasedMarch 6, 2015 (2015-03-06)Genre Pop EDM Length3:21LabelInterscopeSongwriter(s) Madonna Tim Bergling Arash Pournouri Salem Al Fakir Magnus Lidehäll Vincent Pontare Producer(s) Madonna Avicii Salem Al Fakir Magnus Lidehäll Vincent Pontare Rebel Heart track listing24 tracks…

Kingdom of ThailandMinistry of FinanceกระทรวงการคลังKrasuang Kan KhlangThe Seal of the Bird of Paradise used as the Ministry's sealMinistry of FinanceMinistry overviewFormed14 April 1875; 148 years ago (1875-04-14)Preceding agenciesMinistry of TreasuryDepartment of TreasuryJurisdictionGovernment of ThailandHeadquartersPhaya Thai, BangkokAnnual budget242,948M baht (FY2019)Ministers responsibleSrettha Thavisin, Minister of FinancePrasong Poontaneat, Pe…

1982 Soviet crewed spaceflight to Salyut 7 Soyuz T-6COSPAR ID1982-063A SATCAT no.13292Mission duration7 days, 21 hours, 50 minutes, 52 secondsOrbits completed125 Spacecraft propertiesSpacecraft typeSoyuz-TManufacturerNPO EnergiaLaunch mass6,850 kilograms (15,100 lb) CrewCrew size3MembersVladimir DzhanibekovAleksandr IvanchenkovJean-Loup ChrétienCallsignPamir (Pamirs) Start of missionLaunch date24 June 1982, 16:29:48 (1982-06-24UTC16:29:48Z) UTCRocketSoyuz-ULau…

Japanese anime television series Gamba no BōkenGamba and his friendsガンバの冒険(Ganba no Bouken)GenreAdventureCreated byAtsuo Saitō Anime television seriesDirected byOsamu DezakiProduced byTooru UenoSankichirou KusubeWritten byMitsuru MajimaYutaka KanekoSouji YoshikawaHideo TakayashikiAtsushi YamatoyaYoshio TakeuchiMusic byTakeo YamashitaStudioTMS EntertainmentMadhouseOriginal networkNippon TVOriginal run April 7, 1975 – September 29, 1975Episodes26 Anime film…

ClippertonÎle de Clipperton / Île de la PassionGeografia fisicaLocalizzazioneOceano Pacifico Coordinate10°18′15″N 109°13′09″W / 10.304167°N 109.219167°W10.304167; -109.219167Coordinate: 10°18′15″N 109°13′09″W / 10.304167°N 109.219167°W10.304167; -109.219167 Superficie8,9 km² Sviluppo costiero12 km Altitudine massima29 m s.l.m. Geografia politicaStato Francia DemografiaAbitanti0 Cartografia Clipperton voci di isole della Fr…

American politician Samuel M. ShortridgeUnited States Senatorfrom CaliforniaIn officeMarch 4, 1921 – March 4, 1933Preceded byJames D. PhelanSucceeded byWilliam G. McAdoo Personal detailsBorn(1861-08-03)August 3, 1861Mount Pleasant, Iowa, U.S.DiedJanuary 15, 1952(1952-01-15) (aged 90)Atherton, California, U.S.Political partyRepublicanRelativesClara S. Foltz (sister) Charles M. Shortridge (brother) Samuel Morgan Shortridge (August 3, 1861 – January 15, 1952) was a Re…

عنتمساجد خراسان الرضوية الجامع الكبير كاشمر الجامع الكبير نيسابور العتبة الرضوية المسجد الخشبي ضريح الشيخ أحمد جامي ضريح حسن المدرس قبر ومسجد قطب الدين حيدر مجمع كوشك مسجد قدمغاه مسجد حاجي جلال مسجد حطيطة مسجد خسرو شير مسجد زيرك أباد مسجد شهر أباد مسجد كبود غنبد مسجد جوهرش…

Questa voce sull'argomento registi tedeschi è solo un abbozzo. Contribuisci a migliorarla secondo le convenzioni di Wikipedia. Hermine Huntgeburth alla serata di premiazione dei Grimme Preis del 2015 Hermine Huntgeburth (Paderborn, 13 novembre 1957) è una regista e sceneggiatrice tedesca. Indice 1 Biografia 2 Filmografia parziale 3 Note 4 Altri progetti 5 Collegamenti esterni Biografia Si è diplomata alla Scuola Superiore per il Cinema di Amburgo e grazie una borsa di studio del Servizio…

Fictional character from Investiture of the Gods Relief of Pipa Jing Spirit Pipa Jing (Chinese: 琵琶精; pinyin: Pípa Jīng), or Wang Guiren (Chinese: 王貴人; pinyin: Wáng Guìrén), is a character featured within the classic Chinese novel Fengshen Yanyi (Investiture of the Gods).[1] She is a yaojing (seductive spirit) transformed from a jade pipa after thousands of years of cultivation. She later becomes a favored concubine of King Zhou of Shang.[2] In Fen…

Species of fish Bull trout Conservation status Vulnerable  (IUCN 2.3)[1] Secure  (NatureServe)[2] Scientific classification Domain: Eukaryota Kingdom: Animalia Phylum: Chordata Class: Actinopterygii Order: Salmoniformes Family: Salmonidae Genus: Salvelinus Species: S. confluentus Binomial name Salvelinus confluentusSuckley, 1859[3] The bull trout (Salvelinus confluentus) is a char of the family Salmonidae native to northwestern North America.[4] His…

Kembali kehalaman sebelumnya