Share to: share facebook share twitter share wa share telegram print page

Welfare's effect on poverty

The relationship between poverty reduction and differing levels of welfare expense as a percentage of GDP[1]

The effects of social welfare on poverty have been the subject of various studies.[1]

Studies have shown that in welfare states, poverty decreases after countries adopt welfare programs.[2] Empirical evidence suggests that taxes and transfers considerably reduce poverty in most countries whose welfare states commonly constitute at least a fifth of GDP.[3][4][5][6][7][8] In 2013, the Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development asserted that welfare spending is vital in reducing the ever-expanding global wealth gap.[9]

At the same time, the relationship between welfare and poverty is subject to many exogenous factors including the social determinants of poverty, welfare regime type, and the degree of systemic social, economic, and political prejudice against those living in poverty.[10] Thus, while comparative studies in and across different welfare states point to an overall positive effect (that is, welfare reduces poverty), careful attention is required to the differences between welfare states in order to determine to what extent social policies are and are not effective.

Empirical Studies

Countries' income inequality as of 2018 according to their Gini coefficients[11]
World map indicating the Human Development Index in 2015

Quantitative measurement of the impact of welfare programs on poverty provides different estimates depending on the study design and available dataset. Many studies look at the net impact of tax and transfer programs on relative poverty as disaggregated analysis requires substantial amounts of high-quality data and robust estimation methods.[12] Below are examples of notable studies that underscore the complexity of evaluating the direct causal mechanisms by which a welfare state reduces poverty.

Smeeding - "Poor People in Rich Nations" (2006)

Timothy Smeeding used data from the Luxembourg Income Study to determine the effectiveness of anti-poverty and welfare programs on poverty reduction. The data for all the countries was from the year 2000 with the exception of the United Kingdom and the Netherlands for which the data was from 1999.[1] Smeeding concluded that post-tax transfer payments reduced both relative and absolute poverty levels in every country for which data was available, however, with significant variation between countries.

Country Social expenditures on non-elderly[1][Notes 1]
(as percentage of GDP)
Total percent of
poverty reduced[1]
 United States 2.3 26.4
 Netherlands 9.6 65.2
 Sweden 11.6 77.4
 Germany 7.3 70.5
 Canada 5.8 46.0
 Finland 10.9 69.7
 United Kingdom 7.1 60.1
 Belgium 9.3 76.9
 Austria 7.4 75.8
 Italy 4.3 57.7
 Ireland 5.5 44.1
Average 7.4 60.9

Kenworthy (1999) and Bradley et al. (2003)

The absolute poverty rates of various countries before and after their introduction of welfare[2]
The relative poverty rates before and after the introduction of welfare of various countries[4]

Two studies compare countries internationally before and after implementing social welfare programs. Using data from the Luxembourg Income Study, Bradley et al. and Lane Kenworthy measure the poverty rates both in relative terms (poverty defined by the respective governments) and absolute terms (poverty defined by 40% of United States median income), respectively. Kenworthy's study also adjusts for economic performance and shows that the economy made no significant difference in uplifting people out of poverty.

The studies look at the different countries from 1960 to 1991 (Kenworthy) and from 1970 to 1997 (Bradley et al.). Both these periods are roughly when major welfare programs were implemented such as the War on Poverty in the United States. The results of both studies show that poverty has been significantly reduced during the periods when major welfare programs were created.

Country Absolute poverty rate (1960–1991)
(threshold set at 40% of United States median household income)[2]
Relative poverty rate

(1970–1997)[4]

Pre-welfare Post-welfare Pre-welfare Post-welfare
 Sweden 23.7 5.8 14.8 4.8
 Norway 9.2 1.7 12.4 4.0
 Netherlands 22.1 7.3 18.5 11.5
 Finland 11.9 3.7 12.4 3.1
 Denmark 26.4 5.9 17.4 4.8
 Germany 15.2 4.3 9.7 5.1
  Switzerland 12.5 3.8 10.9 9.1
 Canada 22.5 6.5 17.1 11.9
 France 36.1 9.8 21.8 6.1
 Belgium 26.8 6.0 19.5 4.1
 Australia 23.3 11.9 16.2 9.2
 United Kingdom 16.8 8.7 16.4 8.2
 United States 21.0 11.7 17.2 15.1
 Italy 30.7 14.3 19.7 9.1

Korpi and Palme - The Paradox of Redistribution (1998)

In their groundbreaking 1998 study "The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of Equality", Walter Korpi and Joakim Palme constructed a model to test the redistributive efficiency of targeted and universal social welfare policies on reduction of poverty and income inequality.[13] Using data from 18 OECD countries and the Luxembourg Income Study, Korpi and Palme identified a typology of five "ideal" social insurance institutions that can serve as the basis for evaluating the degree to which different welfare states are successful in achieving their redistributive goals.

Institution/Model Bases of Entitlement to Welfare Benefit-Level Principle Employer-Employee Cooperation in Program Governance
Targeted Proven need Minimum No
Voluntary state-subsidized Membership, contributions Flat-rate or earnings-related No
Corporatist Occupational category and labor force participation Earnings-related Yes
Basic security Citizenship or contributions Flat-rate No
Encompassing Citizenship and labor force participation Flat-rate and earnings-related No

Korpi and Palme highlighted the complexity of institutional structures of welfare states in that different states will have different combinations of institutional types for a given social welfare program. Nevertheless, the authors also argued that each welfare typology "can be expected to affect redistributive processes through differences in the role they accord to markets and to politics" as, for instance, the targeted model resembles a "Robin Hood" strategy whereas the basic security model reflects a "simple egalitarian strategy".

Examining the relative impact of these models, Korpi and Palme found that the redistributive efficiency of providing high-income earners with earnings-related benefits (e.g. private pensions) is higher than that of flat-rate (where everyone gets the same amount) or targeted (means-tested) benefits. This finding complicates the traditional hypothesis that a more generous welfare state will have been more successful at reducing income inequality and poverty; Korpi and Palme argue that this is due to three overlooked circumstances:

  1. The size of the redistributive budget, that is, the amount invested in welfare programs, is not fixed and tends to vary depending on the type of welfare institutions in a country.
  2. There is often a trade-off between the extent of targeting benefits for low-income individuals/households and the size of redistributive budgets.
  3. The outcomes of market-based distribution (opposite of the decommodification of welfare) tend to be more unequal than the distribution of earnings-related social insurance programs due in part to the inability of lack of willingness to acquire private earnings-related insurance and social stratification.

These findings led to what Korpi and Palme titled the paradox of redistribution:

"The more we target benefits at the poor only and the more concerned we are with creating equality via equal public transfers to all, the less likely we are to reduce poverty and inequality [...] if we attempt to fight the war on poverty through target-efficient benefits concentrated on the poor, we may win some battle, but we will probably lose the war. Universalism is not enough, however. To be effective, universalism must be combined with a strategy of equality that comes closer to the preaching of Matthew than to the practices in Sherwood Forest"

Criticisms and counterpoints

Decline in American welfare benefits since 1962 (in 2006 dollars)[14]

In the United States, some members of both the Republican Party[15] and Democratic Party,[16] as well as third parties such as the Libertarian Party,[17] have favored reducing or eliminating welfare. The landmark piece of legislation which reduced welfare was the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Act under the Clinton administration.

Conservative groups such as The Heritage Foundation[18] argue that welfare creates dependence, a disincentive to work and reduces the opportunity of individuals to manage their own lives.[19] This dependence is called a "culture of poverty", which is said to undermine people from finding meaningful work.[20] Many of these groups also point to the large budget used to maintain these programs and assert that it is wasteful.[18]

According to a June 2015 report by the IMF, the defining challenge of our time is widening income inequality. In advanced economies, the gap between the rich and poor is at its highest level in decades. Inequality trends have been more mixed in emerging markets and developing countries (EMDCs), with some countries experiencing declining inequality, but pervasive inequities in access to education, health care, and finance remain.[21]

Some socialists and Marxists argue that welfare states and modern social democratic policies limit the incentive system of the market by providing things such as minimum wages, unemployment insurance, taxing profits and reducing the reserve army of labor, resulting in capitalists having little incentive to invest. In essence, social welfare policies cripple the capitalist system and increase poverty. By implementing public or cooperative ownership of the means of production, some socialists believe there will be no need for a welfare state.[22][23]

Critics of welfare claim that too little of the transferred income actually reaches poor people, that the safety net welfare provides creates a "poverty trap" by reducing the initiative of poor people, and that welfare weakens the economy.[2]

A 2010 study examining the effects of the Personal Responsibility and Work Opportunity Reconciliation Act of 1996 found that the act's "welfare cutbacks did not increase poverty rates."[24]

Larry Summers estimated in 2007 that the lower 80% of families were receiving $664 billion less income than they would be with a 1979 income distribution, or approximately $7,000 per family.[25] Not receiving this income may have led many families to increase their debt burden, a significant factor in the 2007–2009 subprime mortgage crisis, as highly leveraged homeowners suffered a much larger reduction in their net worth during the crisis. Further, since lower income families tend to spend relatively more of their income than higher income families, shifting more of the income to wealthier families may slow economic growth.[26][specify]

Public opinion

A January 2014 Pew Research poll found that 49% of Americans believe government aid to the poor does more good than harm as people can not escape poverty until basic needs are met and 54% believe taxes should be increased on the wealthy and corporations to expand anti-poverty programs.[27]

In 2019, the Cato Institute's "Welfare, Work, and Wealth National Survey" concluded that an overwhelming majority of Americans believe the government to be incapable of fighting poverty and that existing welfare expenditures are insufficient or inefficiently distributed. 70% of respondents, across the political spectrum, perceive addressing the underlying causes of poverty to be more important than increases to anti-poverty welfare initiatives. The same study also found that 79% of those surveyed favor "economic growth" as a potential solution to the poverty cycle over welfare spending.[28]

Poverty's effect on welfare

While the effect of social welfare on poverty has been documented across both quantitative and qualitative studies, consideration of reverse causality is important in understanding the extent to which welfare can address poverty. In other words, the perception of poverty and the poor can determine the degree to which the welfare state is willing to address poverty. For example, the cultural shift towards viewing poverty as an issue of "behavioral dependency" of deficiency directly influenced the reduction of entitlement welfare pushed by the Clinton Administration in the PRWORA.[29] The transition from "welfare" to "workfare" is of particular interest to feminist scholars and social scientists who link preconceived ideas about the poor, moral anxiety around teenage pregnancy (read women's bodies and reproductive role), reproducing white supremacy, and reinforcing capitalism, to the welfare reform of the 20th-century.[30]

Welfare stigma (historically expressed and experienced as the pejorative welfare queen and welfare mother labels) further exacerbates the socioeconomic factors mediating the impact of welfare. Social stigma is prevalent towards recipients of public assistance programs. The value of self-reliance is often at the center of feelings of shame and the fewer people value self reliance the less stigma effects them psychologically.[31][32] Stigma towards welfare recipients has been proven to increase passivity and dependency in poor people and has further solidified their status and feelings of inferiority.[31][33] Caseworkers frequently treat recipients of welfare disrespectfully and make assumptions about deviant behavior and reluctance to work. Many single mothers cited stigma as the primary reason they wanted to exit welfare as quickly as possible.[31] Recipients of public assistance are viewed as objects of the community rather than members allowing for them to be perceived as enemies of the community which is how stigma enters collective thought.[34] Amongst single mothers in poverty, lack of health care benefits is one of their greatest challenges in terms of exiting poverty.[31] Traditional values of self reliance increase feelings of shame amongst welfare recipients making them more susceptible to being stigmatized.[31] Studies show that U.S. states with stronger anti-welfare sentiment amplify the experience of welfare stigma, especially along the lines of race, ethnicity, and education.[35]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ This includes cash and near-cash spending (such as TANF and food stamps) and spending for public housing. It excludes healthcare and education spending.

References

  1. ^ a b c d e Smeeding, Timothy (2006). Poor People in Rich Nations: The United States in Comparative Perspective. Table 4, "The Antipoverty Effect of Government Spending: Percent of All Persons Poor". Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 20, Number 1—Winter 2006 —Pp. 69 –90.
  2. ^ a b c d Kenworthy, L. (1999). Do social-welfare policies reduce poverty? A cross-national assessment. Social Forces, 77(3), 1119–39.
  3. ^ Woolf, Steven; Aaron, Laudon. "U.S. Health in International Perspective". National Research Council and Institute of Medicine. pp. 171–72. Retrieved April 8, 2013.
  4. ^ a b c Bradley, D.; Huber, E.; Moller, S.; Nielson, F.; Stephens, J. D. (2003). "Determinants of Relative Poverty in Advanced Capitalist Democracies". American Sociological Review. 68 (3): 22–51. doi:10.2307/3088901. JSTOR 3088901.
  5. ^ Kevin Drum (26 September 2013). We Can Reduce Poverty If We Want To. We Just Have To Want To. Mother Jones. Retrieved 28 September 2013.
  6. ^ Gould, Elise and Wething, Hilary (24 July 2012). "U.S. poverty rates higher, safety net weaker than in peer countries." Economic Policy Institute. Retrieved 26 July 2013.
  7. ^ Zachary A. Goldfarb (9 December 2013). Study: U.S. poverty rate decreased over past half-century thanks to safety-net programs. The Washington Post. Retrieved 15 January 2015.
  8. ^ Kenworthy, Lane (February 2014). America's Social Democratic Future. Foreign Affairs. Retrieved 8 February 2014. See also: Kenworthy, Lane (2014). Social Democratic America. Oxford University Press. ISBN 0199322511
  9. ^ Wealth Gap Widens In Rich Countries As Austerity Threatens To Worsen Inequality: OECD. The Huffington Post. Retrieved 26 July 2013.
  10. ^ Gugushvili, D., Laenan, T. (2021). Two decades after Korpi and Palme's "paradox of redistribution": What have we learned so far and where do we take it from here?. Journal of International and Comparative Social Policy, 37(2), pp. 112-127. doi: 10.1017/ics.2020.24
  11. ^ "GINI index (World Bank estimate) | Data". data.worldbank.org. Retrieved 2020-07-23.
  12. ^ Nelson, Kenneth (November 2004). "Mechanisms of poverty alleviation: anti-poverty effects of non-means-tested and means-tested benefits in five welfare states". Journal of European Social Policy. 14 (4): 371–390. doi:10.1177/0958928704046879. ISSN 0958-9287.
  13. ^ Korpi, Walter; Palme, Joakim (1998). "The Paradox of Redistribution and Strategies of Equality: Welfare State Institutions, Inequality, and Poverty in the Western Countries". American Sociological Review. 63 (5): 661–687. doi:10.2307/2657333. ISSN 0003-1224. JSTOR 2657333.
  14. ^ 2008 Indicators of Welfare Dependence Figure TANF 2.
  15. ^ Republican Party on Welfare & Poverty, On The Issues
  16. ^ Democratic Party on Welfare & Poverty, On The Issues
  17. ^ Issues: Poverty and Welfare
  18. ^ a b Confronting the Unsustainable Growth of Welfare Entitlements: Principles of Reform and the Next Steps", The Heritage Foundation
  19. ^ Tanner, Michael (2008). "Welfare State". In Hamowy, Ronald (ed.). The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE; Cato Institute. pp. 540–42. doi:10.4135/9781412965811.n327. ISBN 978-1-4129-6580-4. LCCN 2008009151. OCLC 750831024.
  20. ^ Niskanen, A. Welfare and the Culture of PovertyThe Cato Journal Vol. 16 No. 1
  21. ^ Era Dabla-Norris; Kalpana Kochhar; Nujin Suphaphiphat; Frantisek Ricka; Evridiki Tsounta (June 15, 2015). Causes and Consequences of Income Inequality : A Global Perspective. International Monetary Fund. Retrieved June 16, 2015.
  22. ^ Encyclopedia of Marxism: Glossary of Terms
  23. ^ Wolff, Richard D. (15 April 2013). A New Political Strategy. Democracy at Work. Retrieved 28 July 2013. "...the best solutions to pressing social problems lie in going well beyond the state and welfare ("socialist") reforms of the past in the precise sense of changing the organization of enterprises, democratizing them into WSDEs (workers' self-directed enterprises)."
  24. ^ Borjas, George J. (November 22, 2015). "Does welfare reduce poverty?" (PDF). Research in Economics.
  25. ^ Larry Summers. "Harness market forces to share prosperity". Retrieved 21 September 2015.
  26. ^ Mian, Atif; Sufi, Amir (2014). House of Debt. University of Chicago. ISBN 978-0-226-08194-6.
  27. ^ Most See Inequality Growing, but Partisans Differ over Solutions. Pew Research Center, 23 January 2014. Retrieved 26 January 2014.
  28. ^ Ekins, E. (2019). What Americans Think About Poverty, Wealth, and Work: Findings from the Cato Institute 2019 Welfare, Work, and Wealth National Survey [White Paper]. https://www.cato.org/sites/cato.org/files/2019-09/Cato2019WelfareWorkWealthSurveyReport%20%281%29.pdf
  29. ^ Lister, Ruth (2021). Poverty (2nd ed.). Cambridge, UK: Polity Press. ISBN 9780745645964.
  30. ^ Briggs, Laura (2017). How all politics became reproductive politics: from welfare reform to foreclosure to Trump. Reproductive justice : a new vision for the twenty-first century. Oakland, California: University of California Press. ISBN 978-0-520-95772-5.
  31. ^ a b c d e Rogers-Dillon, Robin (1 December 1995). "The dynamics of welfare stigma". Qualitative Sociology. 18 (4): 439–456. doi:10.1007/BF02404490. ISSN 1573-7837. S2CID 144636532.
  32. ^ "How Long-Term Unemployment May Mess with Your Mental Health". Psych Central. 2021-11-05. Retrieved 2023-10-24.
  33. ^ Drasch, Katrin (2019). "The social stigma of unemployment: consequences of stigma consciousness on job search attitudes, behaviour and success".
  34. ^ Davis, Liane V.; Hagen, Jan L. (26 July 2016). "Stereotypes and Stigma: What's Changed for Welfare Mothers". Affilia. 11 (3): 319–337. doi:10.1177/088610999601100304. S2CID 144933839.
  35. ^ Lapham, Jessica; Martinson, Melissa L. (2022-06-01). "The intersection of welfare stigma, state contexts and health among mothers receiving public assistance benefits". SSM - Population Health. 18: 101117. doi:10.1016/j.ssmph.2022.101117. ISSN 2352-8273. PMC 9127679. PMID 35620484.
Read more information:

James Meredith James Meredith bermain untuk York City melawan Sunderland, 2011Informasi pribadiNama lengkap James MeredithTanggal lahir 5 April 1988 (umur 35)Tempat lahir Albury, AustraliaTinggi 179 cm (5 ft 10 in)Posisi bermain BekInformasi klubKlub saat ini MillwallNomor 3Karier senior*Tahun Tim Tampil (Gol)2017 – Millwall 46 (0)Tim nasional2015 – Australia 2 (0) * Penampilan dan gol di klub senior hanya dihitung dari liga domestik James Meredith (lahir 5 April 1988) ad…

Artur AvilaLahir29 Juni 1979 (umur 44)Rio de Janeiro, BrasilTempat tinggalRio de Janeiro, Brasil dan Paris, PrancisWarga negaraBrasil dan Prancis[1]AlmamaterUniversitas Federal Rio de JaneiroInstituto Nacional de Matemática Pura e AplicadaDikenal atasSistem dinamikaTeori spektrumPenghargaanFields Medal (2014)IAMP Early Career Award (2012)Michael Brin Prize (2011)Herbrand Prize (2009)EMS Prize (2008)Salem Prize (2006)Karier ilmiahBidangMatematikaInstitusiCNRS, IMJ-PRGUniversitas Did…

Gladys May AylwardMisionaris ke TiongkokLahir(1902-02-24)24 Februari 1902Edmonton, LondonMeninggal3 Januari 1970(1970-01-03) (umur 67)TaiwanMakamNew Taipei, TaiwanTempat tinggalTaiwanKebangsaanBritania RayaNama lain艾偉德Warga negaraTiongkokPendidikanSilver Street School, Edmonton, LondonPekerjaanMisionaris KristenOrganisasiGladys Aylward OrphanageDikenal atasThe Inn of the Sixth Happiness berdasarkan hidupnyaKota asalLondon Gladys May Aylward (24 Februari 1902 –…

This article has multiple issues. Please help improve it or discuss these issues on the talk page. (Learn how and when to remove these template messages) The topic of this article may not meet Wikipedia's notability guideline for books. Please help to demonstrate the notability of the topic by citing reliable secondary sources that are independent of the topic and provide significant coverage of it beyond a mere trivial mention. If notability cannot be shown, the article is likely to be merged, …

Lý Tự Trọng (20 Oktober 1914 – 21 November 1931)[1] adalah seorang revolusioner Vietnam, yang dieksekusi oleh Prancis ketika ia baru berusia 17 tahun.[2] Ia dianggap sebagai martir revolusioner. Pada 2010, jasadnya diidentifikasikan di Distrik 10, Ho Chi Minh City, dan ia dikebumikan ulang di kota tempat tinggal orangtuanya, komune Việt Xuyên di distrik Thạch Hà.[3] Referensi ^ Vietnam courier: Volumes 18-19 1982 Ly Tu Trong — a young communis…

Basilika Santa Anna dari KongoGereja Basilika Minor Santa Anna dari Kongo di BrazzavillePrancis: Basilique Sainte-Anne-du-Congocode: fr is deprecated Basilika Santa Anna dari KongoLokasiBrazzavilleNegara Republik KongoDenominasiGereja Katolik RomaArsitekturStatusBasilika minorStatus fungsionalAktifAdministrasiKeuskupan AgungKeuskupan Agung Brazzaville Basilika Santa Anna dari Kongo, Brazzaville (Prancis: Basilique Sainte-Anne-du-Congocode: fr is deprecated ) adalah sebuah gereja basilika mi…

Koordinat: 9°26′N 170°01′E / 9.43°N 170.02°E / 9.43; 170.02 Wotje Munisipalitas dan atolNegara Kepulauan MarshallKepulauanRatakLuas • Total8 km2 (3 sq mi)Populasi (2011) • Total859 • Kepadatan110/km2 (280/sq mi)Kode ISO 3166-2MH-WTJ Atol Wotje adalah salah satu munisipalitas dan atol di Kepulauan Marshall. Menurut sensus 2011, Wotje memiliki luas 8 kilometer persegi dan populasi 859 jiwa. Kode ISO 3…

BackflowPoster promosiJudul asli역류 GenreKeluargaMelodramaPembuatChoi Yong-wonDitulis olehKim Ji-yeonSeo Shin-hyeSutradaraBae Han-cheolKim Mi-sookPemeranShin Da-eunLee Jae-hwangKim Hae-inSeo Do-youngNegara asalKorea SelatanBahasa asliKoreaJmlh. episode119ProduksiProduser eksekutifLee Min-sookDurasi35 menitRumah produksiMBC C&IDistributorMBCRilis asliJaringanMBC TVFormat gambar1080i (HDTV)Format audioDolby DigitalRilis13 November 2017 (2017-11-13) –26 April 2018 (2018-4-26…

Patung Rollo dari Normandy, pendiri Kadipaten Normandy. Adipati Normandy (Bahasa Prancis: Duc de Normandie) adalah gelar yang dipegang oleh berbagai penguasa Normandy, Inggris, Prancis dan Britania Raya dari abad ke-10 sampai sampai akhir keberadaan monarki di Prancis. Gelar ini merujuk kepada wilayah Normandy di Prancis dan Kepulauan Channel di Selat Inggris. Kepulauan Channel (kecuali Chausey yang berada di bawah kedaulatan Prancis) menyatakan kesetiaan mereka kepada Ratu Elizabeth II dari Bri…

Artikel ini mengenai Allah dalam istilah Kekristenan di Indonesia dan bukan mengenai Allah, Tuhan dalam Islam. Untuk pemahaman lebih lanjut, lihat artikel Penggunaan Allah bagi umat Kristen Indonesia. Halaman ini berisi artikel tentang istilah dalam teologi Kristen. Untuk nyanyian atau pendarasan dalam liturgi, lihat Agnus Dei. Seekor domba yang memegang sebuah panji Kristen merupakan simbol khas Agnus Dei. Anak Domba Allah (bahasa Yunani: Ἀμνὸς τοῦ Θεοῦ, Amnos tou Theou; Lat…

Strada statale 405di Val GerolaDenominazioni successiveStrada provinciale 7 della Val Gerola LocalizzazioneStato Italia Regioni Lombardia DatiClassificazioneStrada statale InizioMorbegno FineGerola Alta Lunghezza17,750[1] km Provvedimento di istituzioneD.M. 27/8/1962 - G.U. 283 dell'8/11/1962[2] GestoreTratte ANAS: nessuna (dal 2001 la gestione è passata alla Provincia di Sondrio) Manuale La ex strada statale 405 di Val Gerola (SS 405), ora strada provinciale 7 della V…

American professional golfer (1929–2016) For the golf tournament, see Arnold Palmer Invitational. For the drink, see Arnold Palmer (drink). For the British real tennis player, see Arnold Palmer (tennis). Arnold PalmerPalmer while in the U.S. Coast Guard, 1953Personal informationFull nameArnold Daniel PalmerNicknameThe KingBorn(1929-09-10)September 10, 1929Latrobe, Pennsylvania, U.S.DiedSeptember 25, 2016(2016-09-25) (aged 87) Pittsburgh, Pennsylvania, U.S.Height5 ft 10 in (178&#…

AubervilliersNegaraPrancisArondisemenSaint-DenisAntarkomunePlaine CommuneKode INSEE/pos93001 /  Aubervilliers merupakan sebuah komune di pinggiran timur laut Paris, Prancis. Terletak 7.2 km (4.5 mil) dari pusat kota Paris. Merupakan salah satu kotamadya terpadat di Eropa. Pusat data Telecity Paris yang memiliki server Wikimedia terletak di Aubervilliers. Nama Pada Abad Pertengahan nama Aubervilliers tercatat sebagai Alberti Villare, berarti kediaman (villare) Adalbert. Adalbert adalah …

Bagian dari seriIslam Rukun Iman Keesaan Allah Malaikat Kitab-kitab Allah Nabi dan Rasul Allah Hari Kiamat Qada dan Qadar Rukun Islam Syahadat Salat Zakat Puasa Haji Sumber hukum Islam al-Qur'an Sunnah (Hadis, Sirah) Tafsir Akidah Fikih Syariat Sejarah Garis waktu Muhammad Ahlulbait Sahabat Nabi Khulafaur Rasyidin Khalifah Imamah Ilmu pengetahuan Islam abad pertengahan Penyebaran Islam Penerus Muhammad Budaya dan masyarakat Akademik Akhlak Anak-anak Dakwah Demografi Ekonomi Feminisme Filsafat Ha…

Italian cardinal His EminenceSilvano Maria TomasiC.S.CardinalSpecial Delegate to the Knights of MaltaApostolic Nuncio Emeritus to the United Nations in GenevaTomasi in Marrakech.ChurchRoman Catholic Church.Appointed1 November 2020Retired13 February 2016PredecessorGiovanni Angelo BecciuOther post(s)Cardinal-Deacon of San Nicola in Carcere (2020-)OrdersOrdination31 May 1965by Joseph Maria PerniconeConsecration17 August 1996by Angelo SodanoCreated cardinal28 November 2020by FrancisRankCar…

Tampilan salah satu aplikasi web. Dalam rekayasa perangkat lunak, suatu aplikasi web (bahasa Inggris: web application atau sering disingkat webapp) adalah suatu aplikasi yang diakses menggunakan penjelajah web melalui suatu jaringan seperti Internet atau intranet. Ia juga merupakan suatu aplikasi perangkat lunak komputer yang dikodekan dalam bahasa yang didukung penjelajah web (seperti ASP, Perl, Java, Java Script, PHP, Python, Ruby, dll) dan bergantung pada penjelajah tersebut untuk menampilkan…

العلاقات الفيجية الكمبودية فيجي كمبوديا   فيجي   كمبوديا تعديل مصدري - تعديل   العلاقات الفيجية الكمبودية هي العلاقات الثنائية التي تجمع بين فيجي وكمبوديا.[1][2][3][4][5] مقارنة بين البلدين هذه مقارنة عامة ومرجعية للدولتين: وجه المقارنة فيجي كمبو…

Об экономическом термине см. Первородный грех (экономика). ХристианствоБиблия Ветхий Завет Новый Завет Евангелие Десять заповедей Нагорная проповедь Апокрифы Бог, Троица Бог Отец Иисус Христос Святой Дух История христианства Апостолы Хронология христианства Ранне…

1868 New Jersey gubernatorial election ← 1865 November 3, 1868 1871 →   Nominee Theodore Fitz Randolph John Insley Blair Party Democratic Republican Popular vote 83,955 79,333 Percentage 51.42% 48.58% Governor before election Marcus Lawrence Ward Republican Elected Governor Theodore Fitz Randolph Democratic Elections in New Jersey Federal government U.S. President 1788-89 1792 1796 1800 1804 1808 1812 1816 1820 1824 1828 1832 1836 1840 1844 1848 1852 1856 1860 186…

English philologist Gabriel Turville-PetreTurville-Petre in 1972Born(1908-03-25)25 March 1908Leicestershire, EnglandDied17 February 1978(1978-02-17) (aged 69)Oxford, EnglandSpouse Joan Elizabeth Blomfield ​ ​(after 1943)​Children3, including Thorlac Turville-PetreAwardsGrand Knight's Cross of the Order of the Falcon (1963)Academic backgroundAlma mater Ampleforth College Christ Church, Oxford Academic advisors J. R. R. Tolkien Charles Leslie Wrenn Influence…

Kembali kehalaman sebelumnya